Wednesday, November 5, 2014

Who Pays for Obamacare?

The dust seems to have settled on ACA a bit, so now is probably a good time to look at who's paying for what.   A lot of this question is boring and obvious:  when it comes to things like Medicaid expansion and the exchange subsidies, the answer is simply that we all are.  Revenues for those entitlements come out of the general fund.  Sure, there are a vast array of new taxes and the Great Medicare Advantage Robbery, but ultimately the burden of this stuff is spread, if not exactly evenly, at least widely.

Instead, I'd like to look at just the impact of the parts of ACA that deal with the Qualified Health Plans and the exchange subsidies.  In this case, the burden is far from even.

A quick refresher:  ACA mandates that the vast majority of individual insurance policies be Qualified Health Plans.  QHPs have the following attributes:
  1. They have a mandatory set of coverages, including preventive care, psychiatric care, substance abuse treatment, maternity coverage, and a variety of other women's health coverage.  Those coverages cost something.  Pre-ACA, a lot of that cost was borne by women, who were more expensive to insure.  Now they're borne by both sexes equally.
  2. QHPs are guaranteed issue, which means that poor risks can't be denied coverage.  Again, costs increase.
  3. QHPs have community rating restrictions.  The one with the largest impact is that rating on age is capped at 3 times the rate for the best unadjusted rate in the plan.
I have problems with the mandatory coverages and the size of the community rating cap, but in general these are all reasonable.  But they cost something.  The question is how much, and who pays.

To answer this, let's start with some stats that HHS released in June 2014 (see table 2):
  • Before any subsidies are applied, the average premium for an individual QHP is $346/mo.
  • 87% of all people insured with a QHP through the exchanges received subsidies.
  • Based only on those who received a subsidy, the average subsidy was $264.
  • Therefore, the average subsidy reduced the monthly premium to $82/mo.
Next, we need to know how many people are signed up on the exchanges and how many people have purchased non-group QHPs outside of the exchanges.  This should give us a pretty good number for the total number of people in the individual insurance market.  It's not a perfect number, because it doesn't account for grandfathered non-QHPs.  I'm going to ignore the grandfathered plans on the grounds that I'm trying to find out what QHPs are costing, and who's paying for them.  By the same token, I'm ignoring the vast majority of people who are covered by employer-sponsored group health plans.

This site states that, as of this writing (and the numbers have already been revised down two days later):
  • There are 7.3 million people current on their premiums for policies purchased on the exchanges.
  • There are another 8.0 million who have purchased QHPs off of the exchanges.  By definition, all of these people are not receiving subsidies.
Next, now that we know that the average policy costs, $346/mo, we need to calculate what it would have reasonably cost in the absence of ACA's QHP provisions.  To do that, we first note that, in 2010, before ACA took effect, the Kaiser Family Foundation calculated that the average individual policy premium was $215/mo.

Now, if we know how much that premium would have gone up due to health care cost inflation, we can come up with a "what if there were no ACA" number for the average premium.  Here are some World Bank numbers for 2010-2012 for per-capita health expenditures:

Year Expenditure Percent Change
2010 8254
2011 8467 2.6%
2012 8895 5.1%
2013 9125 (est) 2.6% (est)
2014 9361 (est) 2.6% (est)

I'm using the 2010-2012 average growth to compute the numbers for 2013 and 2014.  When you do the whole thing, growth from 2010 (where we had the average premium of $215) to 2014 is 13.4%.  That would make the new average premium $244.  Note that this number is conservative; in reality, a lot of the per-capita spending growth occurs with the elderly, who are covered by Medicare.  So we might reasonably expect that the "if ACA didn't exist" premium, based solely on cost inflation, could be even lower.

OK, we're getting there.  Now, we know that the average person who got a subsidy probably did very well under ACA.  But what about the people who didn't get a subsidy?  On average, they're paying $346/mo for a QHP, when without the ACA laws they could expect to be paying $244.  So they're paying $102/mo, or $1224/yr, more under ACA.

We're now in a position to calculate the total amount spent on the QHP provisions and subsidies for ACA.

87% of the 7.3M on the exchanges get a subsidy of $264, so 7.3M * 87% * $264/mo * 12 mo = $20.1B/yr in subsidies.  (Note that this number doesn't jibe with the CBO number of $17B in Table 1, presumably because the $20.1B is for a full year and the $17B is for about 7 months of a fiscal year, with February, March, and April having a big ramp-up.)

Then we have 13% of 7.3M = 950K people on the exchanges with no subsidy, and another 8.0M people off-exchange, for a total of 8.9M who are paying the full freight of the new laws, which we computed to be $1224/yr, so they're paying $10.9B/yr.

$20.1B in subsidies + $10.9B for the full freight people = $31.0B a year as the total cost of the QHP and subsidy provisions of ACA.  (Note that I'm leaving out the risk corridor payments.  They make things even worse, but not that much worse.)

Now, I'm going to make the assumption that the $20.1B is distributed evenly across every taxpayer in the US.  The most recent IRS statistics show that the number of returns filed in 2012 as classified by filing status (Excel) shows:

Filing Status Returns Taxpayers
Married Filing Jointly 53.7M 107.4M
Married Filing Separately 2.7M 2.7M
Heads of Household 21.8M 21.8M
Surviving Spouses 0.1M 0.1M
Filing Single 66.7M 66.7M
Total Taxpayers 198.6M

Again, this number is conservative, because it doesn't account for people who paid no federal tax.  But based on this number, every one of those 198.6M taxpayers in the country (feel free to tweak this number up by a bit to account for it being 2014) is paying out $101/yr for the ACA subsidies.  So far so good.

But wait!  The 8.9M people who don't get subsidies are paying not only that $101/yr, they're also paying the $1224/yr for the increased premiums, for a grand total of $1325/yr. That's more than 13 times what the average taxpayer pays.

Put another (and even more horrifying) way, 4% of all taxpayers are paying for 35% 38% of the cost of the QHP and subsidy provisions of ACA.

That doesn't sound very fair, does it?

But maybe those 8.9M are very wealthy, you say.  I don't have any data on the income distribution.  We know that their incomes are greater than 400% of the poverty level, or they'd get subsidies.  But consider the small business owner or the independent contractor.  Some of those people are wealthy, but the vast majority are living solidly middle-class existences.  I'd be surprised if the majority of them made more than $100K/yr.  Those are the people we're burdening with a hefty chunk of this law.

On-balance, I favor a lot of the provisions of the QHP and subsidy portions of ACA.  But if you're going to embark upon this grand redistribution of wealth, the least you can do is spread the burden fairly.


UPDATE 11/8/14:  If you take out the filers with less than $10,000 adjusted gross income, you wind up with about 172M taxpayers.  That's probably a better proxy for who's paying for the general fund stuff.  If you use that number, then every taxpayer is paying $122/yr for the subsidies and the 8.9M full-freight people are paying $1346/yr each, for a total of $12.0B.  So then 5% of taxpayers are paying for 39% of the total.  Not a lot better.

Also fixed computation error (see strikethru).

UPDATE #2:  I found a whole bunch of CMS data on per-capita healthcare spending and consumption (see here, here, and here) and was able to cook it down to get a better number for the 2010-2014 increase in personal health care consumption, ages 0-64 (so no Medicare taken into account).  The number is 16.1%.  Using that number and the 172M taxpayers revision would make the following changes to the model:
  • "What if there is no ACA" average premium: $250/mo.
  • Contribution of excess premiums to total cost of QHP and subsidies: $96/mo/person, $1152/yr/person total $10.3B/yr.
  • Subsidy cost shared by 172M taxpayers:  $117/taxpayer
  • Total cost of QHP and subsidies: $30.4B.
  • Yearly amount paid by full-freight QHP payers: $1275/yr., or $11.3B.
  • So 5% of taxpayers pay 37% of the total cost of ACA.

Tuesday, December 17, 2013

GDP vs. Productivity Growth, Updated

I keep referencing this chart in comments elsewhere, so I thought I'd update it:


GDP and productivity numbers courtesy of the US BEA and BLS.  The moving average and growth rates are courtesy of Excel.

Friday, November 22, 2013

My Love-Hate Relationship With Like

I write a lot more comments on other blogs than I do original posts on this blog.  Given my massive following of 2 people who may or may not have pushed the wrong button somewhere along the way, it seems like a better way of getting other people to see my writing.  If I'm working something new out, I'll write it here.  If I'm merely pontificating on one of the topics du jour, I'll often do it somewhere else.

An odd thing has happened:  On Disqus, my "like"-to-comment ratio has been rising recently, going from considerably less than one to 2.6 as of today.  What changed?

What changed is I started commenting on sites that agreed with me.

It's a small but distinct rush to discover that thirty or forty strangers read my comment, thought to themselves, "Damn, that TRM is really on to something there," and took the vast quantity of effort necessary to reach for the mouse and click the little up-arrow, or thumbs-up icon, just for me.  If I write a popular comment, I'll go back and monitor it.  I certainly want to read response comments, but I have to confess, I love the likes.

Now, when I comment on sites where people disagree with me, I don't get the likes.  It's a bummer.  It makes me less likely to comment again.

This is a terrible dynamic.

It is fair to say that I've learned more when I was wrong on an issue, and sharpened my arguments more when I still thought I was right, by getting ripped by smart people on a site where I'm arguing against the consensus, rather than by receiving the little squirt of "like" dopamine.  But dopamine will do what dopamine does; I find myself spending more time reading, and commenting on, sites where people will reward me.

I've written ad nauseam about the dangers of the self-selecting properties of the blogosphere (my, that word's become somewhat quaint, hasn't it?).  That dynamic existed before social media took over the web, and it was dangerous even back then.  But the invention of the "like" paradigm has distilled the problem down to its essence and provided the ultimate binary self-selector.  If people like you, you come back.  If they don't, you stop coming.

We're going to have to come to grips with the fact that our most powerful communication tools are terrible for public discourse.  I'm not a fan of the bland network news.  (Speaking of which:  is there some kind of new standards and practices edict that requires somebody to lose their shit and sob uncontrollably in at least one segment of each of the ABC/CBS/NBC broadcasts?)  But we sure could use a medium that had a natural tendency to form consensus instead of sharpening contrasts.

Thursday, November 14, 2013

The Semi-Frozen Flounder of Reality

I'm pretty sure that you're not going to learn much new from Jonah Goldberg's indictment of l'affaire Obamacare, but you're going to laugh so hard that you may pop a ligament in your back.

Friday, November 8, 2013

There's a Fairer Way to Do Universal Coverage

I've spent most of the morning wandering through the endless wasteland that is health care insurance analysis.  First observation:  it's so difficult to find a centralized source of data to answer simple questions that only a modicum of paranoia is required before you wonder if obfuscation isn't in a few people's best interests.  Of course, the less paranoid explanation is simply that this thing is so friggin' complex that nobody really knows what's going on.

But I did find some stuff, mostly courtesy of the Kaiser Family Foundation and the CBO.  I know the source of insurance for the US population in 2011:



It's good to know these stats in actual number of people, too:


Employer  149,350,600
Individual  15,416,100
Medicaid  50,670,200
Medicare  39,996,700
Other Public  3,846,400
Uninsured  48,611,600
Total  307,891,600.0

(Note that these are 2011 numbers.  The number of uninsured went down in 2012--see below.)

And, of the uninsured, I know the 2012 income distribution:


I know some other handy facts:

  • There were 47.3 million uninsured in the US in 2011.
  • The average individual health care policy cost $2580/year in 2010.
  • The average group plan policy for a single employee cost $5615/year in 2012 (total of both employer and employee contributions).
  • The average group plan policy for a family cost $15,745/year in 2012 (total of both employer and employee contributions.
  • CBO projected cost of exchange subsidies is $2B for 2012, $4B for 2013, and $25B for 2014.  Let's assume $2B a year for administrative stuff and move the other $2B in 2013 to 2014 to account for the giant ongoing exchange clusterfuck, and we'll use $25B for subsidies in 2014.
  • CBO also projects that one third of the people newly eligible for Medicaid will reside in states that will extend coverage in 2014, another one third will be covered by 2015, and the last third will not be covered ever, or at least until after 2015.  In 2014, CBO estimates that 7 million additional people will be covered by Medicaid.
I think we're ready to do some computation now.  So we have 47M uninsured minus 7M going to Medicaid, for 40 million people to insure in 2014.  Let's suppose we get half of them, taking it down to 20M.

Let's goose the $2580/year for the average individual plan premium in 2010 by, say, 16.7% over the last 3 years making the yearly premium $3010.  At roughly 15 million people in the individual market, we're looking at $45.2B in premiums.  Now we're going to add 20M people to the market who will be, on average, older, sicker, and more pregnant than the current market.  Let's say their unadjusted premiums would be $4000/year.  That's $80 billion more in individual premiums.

So:
  • Total getting individual insurance in 2014:  15M (current) + 20M (new) = 35M.
  • Total amount owed in premiums by those 35M:  $43B (current) + $80B (new) - $25B (subsidies) = $98 billion.  Or, to put it another way, 35M people will pay $55B extra in insurance premiums.
  • That's an average of $1570 to be paid by 11% of the population.
Mind you, we're talking about 11% of the population that is much poorer and much more insecure than the US average.  And we're forcing them to pay an extra $1570.

Let's give these people median household income of $42,000, (US median is $51,000) and the average household size of 2.55.  So $1570 * 2.55 / 42,000 = a 9.5% tax levied on a class of people that are pretty much living hand-to-mouth at best.

In what universe is this fair, to say nothing of compassionate?

Now let's perform a little experiment:  We've got 149 million people who have group insurance worth an average of $15,700 a year per family or, using the same household size (which isn't quite right, because the characteristics of employed households are different from those than are unemployed, but we're going back-of-napkin anyway), $6150 per person.

If, instead of 35M people, we have 149M + 35M = 184M people paying the extra $55B, that amounts to a tax of $299 per person, instead of $1570.  Using the US household median income of $51,000 and 2.55 people per household, you're looking at $299 * 2.55 / 51,000 = a 1.5% tax paid by 60% of the population.

Want to make ACA fair?  Here's what you do:
  1. Get rid of group insurance.
  2. Remove the caps on health savings accounts.
  3. Force employers to contribute the amount that they previously spent on employee to their HSAs.
  4. Everybody buys individual plans.
  5. Keep community rating as-is.
  6. Get rid of these stupid minimum health benefits and bronze/silver/gold/platinum classifications and let people buy the plans they want.
Want to do something even better?  Dump Medicare and Medicaid into the pool at the same time.

This is obviously going to impact more people than the current law.  And the people it's going to impact are a lot more powerful than the lower-middle-class voters you're hitting with ACA right now.  But either something close to universal coverage is a national imperative, or it's not.  This kind of reform wouldn't make ACA a good law.

But at least it wouldn't be an obscenity.

Saturday, November 2, 2013

Snowden-Induced Cognitive Dissonance

I believe both of the following statements:
  1. Edward Snowden is a straight-up traitor, who has done irreparable harm to the national security of the US, and has damaged its diplomatic standing in the world.
  2. Edward Snowden has done the American people a huge service by revealing to them the extent of the modern surveillance state, and by provoking a long-overdue discussion about the tradeoffs we need to make as we balance freedom and security.
Believing both statements makes my head hurt.  Mr. Snowden asking for the US to stop treating him like a traitor makes my head hurt even more, because the derisive laughter it provokes sends little pressure waves through my skull, exacerbating the pain.

I don't buy that Snowden dumped all of the NSA's secrets out of any civic-spirited impulse for one second.  Snowden is a narcissistic sociopath who wanted to be famous.  If anything else were the case, he would have leaked a minimum amount of information anonymously.  He also would have found more benign host countries than China and Russia.

Still, we have to come to grips with the intersection of Big Data and national security.  Evgeny Morozov had an excellent essay on this topic a couple of weeks ago, where he pointed out that the data collection is only a small part of the problem.  The bigger problem is that the data can be processed in ways that can't be understood, either by the watchers or the watched:
Thanks to smartphones or Google Glass, we can now be pinged whenever we are about to do something stupid, unhealthy, or unsound. We wouldn’t necessarily need to know why the action would be wrong: the system’s algorithms do the moral calculus on their own. Citizens take on the role of information machines that feed the techno-bureaucratic complex with our data. And why wouldn’t we, if we are promised slimmer waistlines, cleaner air, or longer (and safer) lives in return?

This logic of preĆ«mption is not different from that of the NSA in its fight against terror: let’s prevent problems rather than deal with their consequences. Even if we tie the hands of the NSA—by some combination of better oversight, stricter rules on data access, or stronger and friendlier encryption technologies—the data hunger of other state institutions would remain. They will justify it. On issues like obesity or climate change—where the policy makers are quick to add that we are facing a ticking-bomb scenario—they will say a little deficit of democracy can go a long way.

Here’s what that deficit would look like: the new digital infrastructure, thriving as it does on real-time data contributed by citizens, allows the technocrats to take politics, with all its noise, friction, and discontent, out of the political process. It replaces the messy stuff of coalition-building, bargaining, and deliberation with the cleanliness and efficiency of data-powered administration.

This phenomenon has a meme-friendly name: “algorithmic regulation,” as Silicon Valley publisher Tim O’Reilly calls it. In essence, information-rich democracies have reached a point where they want to try to solve public problems without having to explain or justify themselves to citizens. Instead, they can simply appeal to our own self-interest—and they know enough about us to engineer a perfect, highly personalized, irresistible nudge.
Thanks to Snowden, we can have discussions like this.  And perhaps because of this, maybe the US should be merciful and ignore the man.  But if he ever comes in easy range of US law enforcement, he must be prosecuted to the full extent of the law.

Now where's that Advil?

Obamacare at the Cusp

I can see the following outcomes from the current crisis in the Affordable Care Act, aka Obamacare:
  1. The exchange starts working, the brouhaha over the baldfaced "if you like your policy you can keep it" lie dies down, and ACA settles into a system that, with a few tweaks, actually works.  (This doesn't mean that it's better than the legacy system; it merely means that it becomes the new normal.)  I'll put the odds of this occurring at about 45%.
  2. The outrage builds and ACA collapses quickly and cleanly, with the legacy system remaining in place.  30% probability.
  3. ACA collapses slowly and messily, taking the legacy system with it, and we wind up with a single payer system.  15% probability.
  4. ACA collapses, takes the legacy system with it, and something new emerges from the rubble.  10% probability.
I support the idea that we don't wheel the gurney out of the ER and dump you in the hospital parking lot if you can't pay, so the most obvious solution to getting near-universal insurance enrollment is excluded.  After that, you can use a single-payer system (Medicaid and Medicare), but that will only work for the genuinely poor and won't cover the young invincibles who've had bad luck.  For them, you can either put a mandate in place (which is what ACA did), or you can do something only slightly more humane than dumping them in the parking lot, namely make medical debts undischargeable through bankruptcy.

Long story short, I think there's nothing wrong in principle with the ACA tripod of mandates, guaranteed issue/community rating, and subsidies.  As for the details, ACA has clearly screwed the pooch.

The pain in the individual insurance market is just the beginning, as Megan McArdle has pointed out:
A lot of folks with employer-sponsored insurance are also going to see their insurance changed, though not quite as quickly. And not “The benefits will get so much more awesome!” but “The Cadillac tax kicked in and we had to drop most of our plans except for the ones with high deductibles.” A friend who sits on the benefits committees of two organizations says that their experts predict that pretty much all plans will end up being of the “consumer-driven” (read: high-deductible) model once the so-called Cadillac tax kicks in.
Let's not kid ourselves:  The ultimate point of this little exercise was to change the incentives in health care enough to put downward pressure on prices, so anybody who thinks this was going to happen without significant pain is an idiot.  The question is whether we're going to get the maximum amount of efficiency for the minimum amount of pain out of this system.  I think the answer to that is going to be a resounding 'no".

Would a single payer system have a lower pain-to-efficiency ratio?  Yes.  But that's not saying much, and the total amount of efficiency generated would still be quite low.  The idea of US single-payer health care scares the shit out of me;  there are too many interest groups and too many providers bellying-up to the public trough to make single-payer anything other than a disaster that simultaneously damages public health while destroying medical innovation, one of the US's core competencies.

Would the legacy system have a lower pain-to-efficiency ratio than ACA?  I honestly don't know.  Certainly not for the poor.  We also have a lot of evidence that the legacy system sucks at controlling costs.  Ultimately, I think that ACA would wind up being a modest improvement, it's so complex that there's no telling what unintended consequence will ooze out of the woodwork next.

And it's possible to do this simply, fairly, and honestly--three adverbs that will never be applied to ACA.  Here are the main principles:
  1. You can't dump most of the cost on the individually insured alone, and you have to be honest with the majority who get their insurance from their employers.  The simplest thing to do is to eliminate group insurance and throw everybody into the individual market.  They won't get as good a deal as they do from a group, but they'll be significantly less screwed than the people in the individual market are right now under ACA.  Let the employers put the money they spend on insurance into a health savings account--that ought to keep the tax incentives about the same.
  2. Keep the mandate.  Keep the subsidies.  But just pay them out of the general fund, with a reasonable income tax increase to cover them.  All this revenue sleight-of-hand is ridiculous.
  3. Keep the exchanges, but get the government out of the business of specifying acceptable insurance plans.  They're not smart enough, or adaptable enough, to understand the market and how it will change in the future.
  4. Stop transferring wealth from the young, who have low incomes and low net worths, to the not-quite-old-enough-to-retire, who have high incomes and high net worths.  For that matter, stop transferring wealth to retirees that have a large enough net worth to fend for themselves.  I'm fine with community rating, as long as you rate in age cohorts.  This is the single most immoral thing in ACA.
  5. Whatever you wind up doing, fold Medicaid and Medicare into it.  Yes, lots of poor people are ignorant and lots of old people are stupid--that's just a fact of life.  If you want to produce a menu of government-approved plans for people who are being 100% subsidized, fine.  If you want to set things up so that they can't use their subsidies for anything other than premiums, also fine.  But this maintenance of five huge health programs (Medicare, Medicaid, individual insurance, group insurance, and price increases caused by the poor defaulting on their medical debts) is just stupid.
  6. Never, ever, ever, allow the government to set prices for medical reimbursement.
You could tweak ACA to do all of this, but the opportunity for new and exotic rent-seeking is much higher doing these kinds of tweaks.  It'd be easier to repeal and replace if Obama's fragile ego would allow it.  But it won't.

As usual, the result will be even messier than what we have now.  Eventually, the incredibly stupid parts of the law will atrophy and we'll hopefully be left with a system something like what I outlined above.  Of course, there will be fifteen completely intolerable sacred cows left over, lovingly maintained by the groups that milk them.  So what else is new?

Sunday, October 13, 2013

How American Political Parties Dissolve

As I write this, the US government has been shut down for two weeks, and we are 4 days away from the "X date" where the Treasury Department runs out of workarounds on the debt ceiling and has to stop paying somebody.  (Odds are that this will not lead to a default on bonds, per the link above, but things are going to be dicey.)  I can't decide whether to call the set of House and Senate Republicans driving the standoff the "Obamacare defunders" over their (now fading) insistence on defunding ACA, or just the "Tea Party"; the two groups may be congruent.  I think I'll settle on the Tea Party, with the proviso that there may be a few Tea Party folks who haven't completely bought into this level of brinksmanship.

There are a lot of theories for why we've gotten into a situation where there appears to be no ZOPA over such a fundamental set of government functions.  Some of the most popular:

  • Republican leadership authority has eroded.
  • This kind of brinksmanship is virtually cost-free for Tea Party representatives in safe districts.
  • This is merely a principled stand against something that's worth risking a financial and/or constitutional crisis.
  • This is an excellent way to demonstrate the irrelevance of the federal government to the average voter, sort of a natural follow-on to the Obama Administration crying wolf over the sequester.
  • This is necessary to re-energize the Republican Party.
All of these reasons have some truth in them, but all of these are iffy propositions.  They're all based on extremely dubious judgment calls.  Politicians are notoriously risk-averse and it's hard to believe very many of them are willing to bet their careers on any of them.  What's going on?

The Tea Party has been heedless of the damage they're doing to the Republican brand.  I think that's because they're no longer concerned with that brand in its current form.  The Tea Party has been essentially conducting an ideological purge, drawing a clear demarcation between "us" and "them".  Any person espousing slightest deviation from Tea Party orthodoxy is labelled "them" and is dismissed.  What remains is a clear minority, but it's a minority with a frightening level of unity.

This seems crazy, but there's one situation where it might be astute:  If the Tea Party believes that the moment has come when it can seize control of the Republican Party, then the gamble might be worth it.  The goal of the shutdown and debt ceiling standoff is then to eject Boehner from the speakership and to eliminate the power of the business conservatives and social moderates in the party.  The Tea Party is effectively seceding from the GOP, but it's hoping to carry off enough support to be able to keep the name and the party infrastructure while changing the ideology.

The US has scant experience with the wholesale dissolution of political parties, but what history tells us is instructive:
  • In the early 1800's, the Federalist and Democratic Republican (aka the Jeffersonian Republican) parties had grown so close together in their positions that several internal schisms arose.  The "corrupt bargain" election of John Quincy Adams in 1824 and the follow-on election of Andrew Jackson in in 1828 shattered the one-party system, leading to the formation of the Democratic party, which supported Jackson's muscular view of executive power, while the Whigs formed around the idea that, well, they didn't like Jackson.  In this case, the Democrats were reacting to the increasing sophistication of the northern financial and industrial system and wanted it stopped.  In short, they had a strong animating principle.  The Whigs formed in an attempt to preserve the emerging institutions, but their only true animating principle was opposition to the reactionary forces mobilized by the Democrats.  The Democrats won, temporarily; they got to keep half of the party name in the divorce.

  • The Whigs finally got an animating principle:  abolition.  By 1840, it was clear that the US was headed for a massive territorial expansion and, absent significant opposition, the new territories were likely to allow slavery.  The Kansas-Nebraska Act in 1854 shattered the Whigs, with the militant abolitionists forming the Republican Party.  We all know how that ended.
The Tea Party thinks they've found their animating principle:  60% of Americans now believe that the federal government has too much power. They hope to forge a new coalition around the intent to reduce the size and power of the feds.

This is a goal that I support.  Note that it is, despite the negative connotations of the word, a "reactionary" goal:  "Government has gotten too big, and we want the trend reversed."  To that extent, the Tea Party's formation looks much like the formation of the Jacksonian Democrats in the late 1820's.  But there was more than one reactionary thread at work in the 1820's.  When the Democrats formed, the top-line issue was about rolling back financial and industrial power.  But the coalition worked because a strong anti-abolition sentiment flowed through the rural and southern factions.  And that issue ultimately overwhelmed the Democratic Party, leading to 1861.

The Tea Party also has other reactionary threads running through it.  Its members are socially conservative, isolationist, and anti-immigration.  They don't like the current US culture.  The subtext here is more diffuse than was the anti-abolition subtext of the Jacksonian Democrats.  The closest you can come to a one-line description would be, "We don't want to live in a sick, militantly secular culture."  But note that, unlike the 1820's and abolition, nobody's threatening to ban religion in the US.  The cultural forces are more complex than that, and the level of support for and against them has a whole bunch of people staking out positions somewhere in the middle.  (I'm one of them.)

If the Tea Party were truly just a small government party, they might easily attract enough factions from the rump of the Republican Party, independents, and conservative Democrats to form a viable party, and the current Republican Party would wither away, in fact if not name.  But the subtext is problematic for them, and their methods make it even more problematic.  It's unlikely that there are enough people willing to save the village by destroying it for their play to work.

So let's summarize the possible outcomes:
  • Tea Party takes over the Republican Party, then attracts enough small-government fellow travelers to make a working near-majority.  (Unlikely, per above.)
  • Tea Party fails to wrest control of the GOP, but winds up destroying it.  A new center-right party forms from the rubble.
  • The GOP establishment acts to crush the Tea Party in short order, leveraging the shutdown debacle to do so.  The Tea Party members capitulate and accept their role as simply a part of the GOP coalition and work to nominate an electable 2016 candidate.  (Note that if this succeeds, Paul Ryan is going to get the lion's share of the credit, and goes to the head of the class for 2016.)
  • Tea Party succeeds in gaining control of the GOP, but dramatically shrinks its influence.  They lose two or three more elections and wither away, then the more moderate elements of the GOP re-establish the status quo ante.
I'm terribly afraid that this last scenario is the most likely, and it's terrible news for the country.  By the time the old conservative coalition recovers from this disruption, we will have had 16 years of a Democratic executive.  Any hope of reining in the government will have gone out the window (if it hasn't already), and we'll be well on our way to the debt crisis that could easily tear the country apart.

A final, cautionary, historical note:  The emergence of the Jacksonian Democrats isn't a definitive event.  Things limp along for 30 years, waiting for the animating oppositional principle (abolition) to become clear.  When it does, the result is the biggest calamity the US has ever faced.  Small government is a fine animating principle, but I have no idea what the principle is that eventually emerges to oppose it.  If history is a guide, we're not going to like the result.

Thursday, August 15, 2013

The NSA, Domestic Surveillance, and the Era of Big Data

I've been off the radar all through l'affaire Snowden, but I've been wrestling with how we should think about this.  Conclusions are a bit thin on the ground, and this post is going to ramble a bit as a result.

First, let's acknowledge that Big Data is going to be the most revolutionary scientific and technological advance of the early 21st century.  Giant, mine-able data sets are already changing how we do biology, sociology, epidemiology, economics, and just about any other -ology or -nomics that you care to name.  Big Data makes problems of intractable complexity suddenly tractable.

And this goes for counterterrorism intelligence analysis as well.  By definition, looking for terrorists is about looking for needles in haystacks.  Big data lets you find needles by looking at how they've changed the shape of the haystack in which they've been placed.  Big Data drastically amplifies the effectiveness of traffic analysis.

So, to the extent that you really, really want to stop every last whack job from setting pressure cookers filled with black powder in public places, then you should be really, really happy that the NSA has mountains of data under its control and the computing power to sift through them.  But of course the fly in the ointment is that "mountains of data under its control" bit.  If they can sift through them looking for terrorists, they can sift through them looking for drug kingpins.  Or child pornographers.  Or embezzlers.  Or Republicans.

Seems to me that this boils down to two basic questions:
  1. Who owns the data set?
  2. What techniques can the owner perform on the data?
We're pretty comfortable these days with businesses owning the data sets that they create during the course of business.  AT&T and Verizon own their call detail records--the ever-popular "metadata" that the Obama Administration has been droning on and on about.  Google owns every search you've ever made and (for a lot of us) every email you've ever sent or received, to say nothing of every four-beer blog post you've made.  And speaking of four beers, Facebook owns every photo of you exercising your constitutional right to join the whoo people from time to time.

We're not exactly happy that these guys own all this stuff, but we're used to it. Why?  Because we trust corporations to mind their business, even when their business is making money off of our semi-public behavior.  Which brings us to the second question:  what limits do we place in the owners of data when they process it?

To answer this question, I like to imagine doing something that I'd be ashamed of (of course this never happens in real life...) and then imagining various people looking at the electronic breadcrumbs.

Do I care if companies provide access to my data for advertising?  If Amazon is trying to sell me a romance novel (hey, my wife and I share an account!), not so much.  But if BDSM-Mart tried to sell me whips and chains, I'd be perturbed.  Is there a difference between these two cases?  Maybe.

First, Amazon tries to sell me things that Amazon sells.  If I didn't do business with Amazon, they wouldn't try to sell me romance novels.  And if Amazon started trying to sell me whips and chains, I'd probably close my account (no doubt causing Amazon's revenues to decline by at least 25%).

On the other hand, BDSM-Mart would have to acquire my data from somebody else.  Maybe they could do this through Google, but Google understands where its bread is buttered and would never give BDSM-Mart direct access to my metadata.  Instead, what they do is allow BDSM-Mart to place advertising with Google, and Google will insert advertising in pages that people whose search and email patterns indicate that they might like bondage paraphernalia.  At no point does Google say, "Hey, BDSM-Mart!  The Radical Moderate looks like he might be a good customer for you!"  If they did, I'd have a big problem with Google.  At the very least, I'd be doing a lot more private browsing, which would hurt Google's revenue.  At the most, I might be complaining to my congressman or filing lawsuits, which, writ large, might put Google out of business.

Next hypothetical:  Imagine two guys at Google's water cooler, swapping stories about those hilarious searches that The Radical Moderate made last week.  Would I be creeped out about this?  The idea doesn't make me happy, but my guess is that if this happens (and maybe Google has a policy about their employees making directed queries and maybe they don't--I'd guess that developers have to make directed queries in the course debugging stuff all the time), they don't talk about me, they talk about me as "some guy".  Do I care now?  Ennh.

Now, let's imagine that somebody in Google takes my data and posts my searches on a public website, with the express purpose of shaming or humiliating me.  That's lawsuit territory, and I'm suing Google, not their employee.  Google has a vested interest in making sure that this doesn't happen, the same way that they're not going to let BDSM-Mart see my data.

Bottom line:  I trust private companies with this sort of data because they value it properly, or they don't remain in business.

But now let's suppose that Google's "customer" is the government.  What kinds of questions can they ask?

Well, some of them might be close to innocuous.  They might want to know the correlation between the number of accounts that search for BDSM stuff and certain types of pornography, for purposes of formulating law enforcement policy.  If all of those correlations are anonymous, no harm done.  But the logical next step isn't so wonderful.  If the feds manage to convince some judge that a certain pattern of BDSM searches indicates that there's a high likelihood that the account will also contain searches for kiddie porn, that would be not so harmless.  I can't imagine a judge issuing a warrant under those circumstances, but you never know--and the way the FISA courts are set up, you never will know.

But notice what had to happen for me to be at risk from the government:  Google had to turn over account-specific information.  So, not only did Google no longer control the data, but they gave it over to somebody who would process it in ways that Google would never dream of.  Here's where the ownership of the data becomes crucial.  Without the data sitting in some server farm controlled by the feds, they can't control the post-processing and queries, and they can't overstep any bounds.

So maybe that's the first step toward a sensible data-mining policy:  the government shouldn't be able to control data.  Or, at the very least, it can't control data with identifiable account info.  The NSA seems to have paid lip-service to anonymizing account info, but it's also pretty clear that the names and addresses were just a protected table, with lots of people able to gain access.  If that information remains safely back with the company that owns it, retrievable only with a warrant, things are somewhat more private.  But we haven't solved the problem of how to keep the feds from mining the anonymous data for whatever they want.

Another possibility is to require warrants for the actual post-processing and search queries.  This is something that would obviously require a pretty sophisticated court (I don't see many judges being able to conduct a code review), but it has the advantage that all data now stays with a private owner.  The feds can donate a firewalled, sterilized server farm to the company for doing the processing, and they can get the anonymous results back.  But the government can't be allowed to own the data, or it will find some way to abuse it.

Does this impede the NSA in its quest to identify real security threats?  It certainly makes the process more ponderous.  If you've got a real-time threat, your engineers aren't going to be able to poke at the data willy-nilly until some interesting answer pops out.  But that's an unlikely way for these guys to work; they're much more likely to come up with specific data-mining programs that they'd like to run on well-established data sets, over a long period of time.  Adding one more hoop to jump through before they conduct this sort of surveillance doesn't seem like a big price to pay.

The much more troubling form of data collection are the taps that the NSA is alleged to have placed to collect raw internet traffic.  There's no way to firewall that sort of collection with a private company.  On the other hand, the only "account" associated with such data is an IP address.  Keeping that information firewalled from the feds without a warrant should allow them to do bulk analysis on the traffic without compromising privacy.  And if they find something alarming, they can get a warrant.

So we can reduce the problem, through fairly simple means, to a question of how much we trust the courts.  Per reports on how FISA courts run currently, the answer to that question is, "not very much".  Fixing the operation of these courts is difficult, but paramount.  At the very least, application for warrants needs to be an adversarial process.  Currently, outside groups can file friend-of-the-court briefs, but it's pretty hard to quash a warrant when you don't know what it's for.  Appointing and providing security clearances for a pool of outside parties with aggressive anti-surveillance agenda would go a long way toward leveling the playing field.  I'd feel a lot better if an EFF lawyer were opposing every warrant application.  I'd gladly contribute to a fund for the billable hours.  (I'd rather not have the feds footing the bill...)

Ultimately, though, we're going to have to live with the fact that applying Big Data techniques to the detritus of daily life potentially gives the government huge power over us.  The only way to prevent that power from being abused will be the exercise of constant vigilance and aggressively proscribing the activities of the security agencies.  I'm not sure I approve of how Snowden outed the whole system, but it's hard to deny that his actions have opened up a very useful conversation.  I just hope that we put some real reforms in place before we all go back to sleep.

Tuesday, May 14, 2013

Neocorticalism and Its Weaknesses

[Blogger's note:  I went dark halfway through writing this.  Started it back in November, then got diverted into a self-imposed software project and lost interest for a while.  Not sure I'm back to blogging for real--we'll see.  No doubt you, my three readers, are incredibly excited!]

Just finished reading [well, last November] Ray Kurzweil's How to Create a Mind.  This has the usual Kurzweillian arguments about why all information technologies--including those associated with biology and neuroscience--grow at an exponential rate, irrespective of the actual technology base.  It extends his singularity books by going a bit deeper into how to build artificial cortical pattern recognizers, and makes the argument that a hierarchy of these modules pretty much constitutes the human mind and its consciousness.

Kurzweil references Jeff Hawkins's On Intelligence, one of my favorite books of all time.  Kurzweil takes issue with some of the details of Hawkins's model, but the two authors both agree on several central points:
  • Both note the existence of a "cortical algorithm", where all areas of the neocortex work pretty much the same and project axons in pretty much the same way.  This means that patterns get recognized the same way everywhere, and project up to higher level pattern recognizers and down to excite, reinforce, or inhibit lower level patterns.
  • Kurzweil thinks that consciousness is an emergent property of a big neocortex, while Hawkins thinks that consciousness is "what it feels like to have a cortex".
  • Both of them spend a lot of time on input pattern recognition, but very little time on motor outputs.
  • Both treat the thalamus and brain stem as I/O devices, with little to do with consciousness (although Kurzweil does note that the thalamus is essential to be conscious).
  • Hawkins thinks that the secret sauce for complex cognition lies in the time-dependent behavior of cortical activation, where pattern #1 primes the downward links for pattern #2 to be activated if things go as the patterns expect them to in the immediate future.  Kurzweil is strangely silent on time-dependent behavior, which is weird, since speech recognition is so heavily time-biased.  I think he's glossing over some behavior of hidden Markov models in which I'm not expert.  He may also be slightly cagey about trade secrets.
I think that they're barking up the right tree with respect to the cortical algorithm, but they're both minimizing the importance of the older brain structures.  I have some trouble with this "neocorticalist" approach.  Here are my big objections:
  • Neocorticalism can't really explain attention.  As I've said before, I think that attention is likely an incredibly ancient property and is intimately involved with consciousness.  I'm prepared to believe that human-style self-reflection and theory of mind might be new, emergent properties, but they can only emerge because of some repurposing of older mechanisms.
  • Simple pattern matching doesn't get you very good motor performance.  I'm prepared to believe that the motor cortex is coordinating intentions and hifgh-level actions, but the whole business seems way too asynchronous to allow us to be catching balls or playing the piano.  The cerebellum is clearly involved, but I suspect that you need a way to make the neocortex semi-synchronous.  There's some evidence that the basal ganglia are involved at least in time perception; I'll bet we're going to discover that the same structures are "clocking" groups of neocortical patterns to coordinate activities in the motor cortex.
  • One of the things that was intriguing about Hawkins's architecture is that it hinted that the learning process self-organized the cortical hierarchy so that novel or unlearned activities were first handled, somewhat hesitantly, at high levels, but the learning process pushed down the salient features into lower level learning, but no mechanism was described for how this happens.  Kurzweil pretty much ignored this, going so far as to posit some kind of central allocator of pattern recognizers.  There's something subtle going on here that pure neocorticalism can't capture.
Since this book was published, Kurweil has taken a high-level technologist position at Google, which has also bought, DNNresearch, Geoff Hinton's startup.  Deep learning, a term coined by Hinton, has been getting a lot of press recently.  It's pretty clear that Google has decided to pour money into this.  It's a problem that's amenable to implementation in cloud computing, so the fit is pretty good.

People implementing deep learning train each layer in a multi-layer network separately, using unsupervised feature detection.  ("Unsupervised" means that you don't tell the layer when it's done something right or wrong--you merely let it classify inputs as it sees fit.)  This still can't be quite what biological systems do, because they can figure out their own layering, which has to be imposed for deep learning.  My guess is that layering in humans is governed by chunks of the cortex that are genetically predisposed to accept axons from I/O-like areas of the thalamus and other parts of the brainstem.  They therefore learn to detect features associated with that kind of input and project out to a more amorphous set of regions, which can then combine multiple projections into novel features.

This still doesn't define a mechanism where layers compete with each other to identify features at the appropriate level of detail, but you can see how that might emerge with enough feedback between layers.

My guess is that we're going to discover that a huge amount of our cognition is dependent on a fairly arbitrary set of input regions mapping to another fairly arbitrary set of cross-regions, and so on.  But note that "arbitrary" doesn't mean that they're not genetically predetermined.  The stability of those mappings across most humans is what allows us to communicate with each other and what allows us to perceive most individuals as "sane".  One of the most interesting things about figuring out how all this hangs together is the possibility of producing entities that think radically differently from us but which still can extract insights about the universe that we're not optimized to perceive.

Things are going to move pretty quickly from here.  We aren't close to a strong AI using this kind of technology, but the Watson/Jeopardy thing shows that you can get an awful lot of interesting work out of something that you wouldn't necessarily want at your dinner party.

Laptop U

The New Yorker has a really excellent summary about taking massively open online courses (MOOCs) into higher ed, and what it will mean to the evolution of both elite and non-elite universities.  The key bit that I hadn't thought about:

“Imagine you’re at South Dakota State,” [Peter Burgard, a professor of German at Harvard] said, “and they’re cash-strapped, and they say, ‘Oh! There are these HarvardX courses. We’ll hire an adjunct for three thousand dollars a semester, and we’ll have the students watch this TV show.’ Their faculty is going to dwindle very quickly. Eventually, that dwindling is going to make it to larger and less poverty-stricken universities and colleges. The fewer positions are out there, the fewer Ph.D.s get hired. The fewer Ph.D.s that get hired—well, you can see where it goes. It will probably hurt less prestigious graduate schools first, but eventually it will make it to the top graduate schools. . . . If you have a smaller graduate program, you can be assured the deans will say, ‘First of all, half of our undergraduates are taking MOOCs. Second, you don’t have as many graduate students. You don’t need as many professors in your department of English, or your department of history, or your department of anthropology, or whatever.’ And every time the faculty shrinks, of course, there are fewer fields and subfields taught. And, when fewer fields and subfields are taught, bodies of knowledge are neglected and die. You can see how everything devolves from there.”
 There's always been a disconnect between MOOCs and basic research, one that I've never been able to resolve.  Since, I'm not really oriented that way, I hadn't thought about the dual problem that occurs in the humanities.

Of course, this implies that humanities teaching needs to be kept alive through constant research and reinterpretation.  I can buy this argument, because teaching stale, received wisdom is going to be so uninspiring to the teachers that the uninspiration will wear off on the students.  It's actually a nifty explanation for why modern humanities teaching gets so wacky:  When all the best re-interpretations have already been taken, you've got to wander out into two- and three-sigma territory to find something new.

Friday, November 9, 2012

...Or Maybe Romney Lost Because His Campaign Was Incompetent

This post on the goat rodeo that was Project ORCA might explain a lot.

By 2PM, I had completely given up. I finally got ahold of someone at around 1PM and I never heard back. From what I understand, the entire system crashed at around 4PM. I'm not sure if that's true, but it wouldn't surprise me. I decided to wait for my wife to get home from work to vote, which meant going very late (around 6:15PM). Here's the kicker, I never got a call to go out and vote. So, who the hell knows if that end of it was working either.
So, the end result was that 30,000+ of the most active and fired-up volunteers were wandering around confused and frustrated when they could have been doing anything else to help. Like driving people to the polls, phone-banking, walking door-to-door, etc. We lost by fairly small margins in Florida, Virginia, Ohio and Colorado. If this had worked could it have closed the gap? I sure hope not for my sanity's sake.
The bitter irony of this entire endeavor was that a supposedly small government candidate gutted the local structure of GOTV efforts in favor of a centralized, faceless organization in a far off place (in this case, their Boston headquarters). Wrap your head around that.
Read the whole thing--this bite only gives you the vaguest flavor of what happened.

Modern presidential campaigns require many of the skills needed by an actual White House staff.  They require vision and strategy.  But the also require superb tactical execution and, newest and perhaps most important, a firm grasp on complex, automated systems design, testing, rollout, and execution.  Based on this description, the Romney campaign utterly failed the test.

I'd be much, much happier with a Romney presidency.  But this is the sort of thing that telegraphs that might have been really screwed up.

A key tenet of the Democratic catechism is that Democrats are smarter than Republicans, and therefore should have more power in governing.  The Project ORCA post-mortem doesn't sound like it's going to do anything to dissuade anybody from thinking that the Democrats are right.

Thursday, November 8, 2012

Mitt Romney Lost Because of Abortion

The despondency, fear, and loathing in the GOP has begun, with a wide range of explanations for Romney's loss in what should have been a slam-dunk year against Obama.  So far, I've seen:
  • The GOP will never win until they have the courage to nominate a conservative.
  • The GOP will never win until they nominate a competent moderate and don't drag him down in the primaries.
  • The GOP will never win until it fixes its core values to appeal to hispanics and women.
  • The Obama campaign had an amazing secret sauce to get out the vote, and the GOP will be fine next time because they'll have the same secret sauce.
  • We're no longer a center-right country, and conservatives need to concentrate on seizing the cultural levers of power.
  • We're no longer a center-right country, so conservatives need to build themselves a parallel society next to the one that's ultimately going to fail.  (If you've got an hour and half to burn, listening to Bill Whittle grope his way toward something coherent on this topic is kind interesting.  I suspect that when he's done with this it won't sound quite as looney as it did in spots.)
  • We're no longer a center-right country, and we're all gonna die.
Some of these are laughable.  Some of them are pretty close to the truth.  Some are... worth deeper consideration.  But I think the most plausible is that the Obama campaign not only had a secret sauce for getting out the vote, but they had a real issue on which to ladle the secret sauce.

The Obama campaign, with a little bit of mind-boggling stupidity from the Republicans, managed to scare women out of their minds, convincing them that Romney was unacceptable.  And they did it over abortion.

I have a wife, two daughters, and a son.  One of my daughters and my son are apolitical--they are, in effect, the dreaded low-information voters, but they don't vote.

My wife also didn't vote, but she's far from a low-information voter.  She's just decided that voting only encourages the bastards, and they're all equally bad.  Plus, we live in Texas.  Why bother, when you know what the result is?

My oldest daughter (she's 31) is well-informed and a regular voter.  She has the handicap of having a BFA from a California art college, so she's been exposed to the absolute worst that liberal academia could possibly throw at her.  However, she's also my daughter, so she's emerged as a relatively centrist, probably slightly left-of-center, voter.

She considered voting for Romney and liked a lot of his economic ideas.  But she ultimately decided that she couldn't vote for him because she was sure that he was going to destroy the reproductive rights infrastructure in the US.  All arguments to the contrary were lost on her.  Romney and the Republicans were just too dangerous even to consider voting for them.  According to her, all of her friends thought the same way.  My wife thought the same way; if she'd voted, she would have voted against Romney for this sole issue.

Now, this is admittedly the smallest sample possible.  And my daughter admittedly is part of the Austin artsy-musician-y community, which is pretty liberal.  But I have a hunch that Obama won the election because of people like her.

The abortion issue poisons all attempts the GOP will make to regain a working electoral majority.  Unmarried women won't vote for them.  Married women who remember the 60's won't vote for them.  Only married women who are happily building families will vote for them.  Since this is a shrinking demographic, the anti-abortion activists in the GOP will manage to lose election after election for their candidates.

I am pro-abortion.  I hate the term "pro-choice" because using it prevents a frank confrontation with the ugly truth about abortion:  It's a way to kill something that would otherwise turn into a human being.  When it comes to things like this, the individual has no "choice"; society gets to make laws that bind its citizens to certain courses of action.  I don't support a burglar's right to choose whether to rip me off; I'm anti-burglary.  I don't support a violent felon's right to choose whether to beat the crap out of me;  I'm anti-battery.  But I'm pro-abortion.

Why?

Before I can explain why, I have to make things worse.  See, I actually believe that a fertilized egg is alive and for all intents and purposes human.  Will all such fertilized eggs implant and start pregnancies?  No.  But hormonal contraception will guarantee that pretty close to 100% of any zygotes that would implant, don't, and die.  Will all pregnancies result in a live birth?  No; about one third of all pregnancies end in spontaneous miscarriage.  But abortion again guarantees that almost 100% of all viable pregnancies against which it is performed will end without a live birth.  (And the small fraction that don't--well, we'll get to that.)

A common "pro-choice" argument is that a blastula, or an embryo, or an early-to-mid-term fetus isn't human because it's not viable ex vivo.  That's certainly true, but a baby isn't viable ex vivo either, without its mother's care.  Yet (almost) all cultures consider babies to be human.  Another argument is that a fetus is something less than human because it lacks many uniquely human features and faculties.  But a baby lacks many of those faculties as well.  And a baby resembles an adult human about as much as a blastula resembles a baby.  Don't think so?  Try touching a baby's arms together above its head.  Babies are born as partially-grown heads with a minimum life-support system.  They don't look or act much like people.  We're awfully fond of them, for powerful evolutionary reasons, but the only thing they have in common with adult humans is a genotype.

So, given all of the above, how can I possibly be pro-abortion?

I'm pro-abortion because we as a society get to decide when the taking of human life is justifiable and when it's murder.  We can kill people in wars and celebrate the people who do so.  We can kill people in defense of ourselves or our families and society holds us blameless.  We execute humans that have done things so heinous that we as a society consider ourselves better off without their continued existence.  We almost always regret the taking of human life, even when justified, but we do it anyway, in some circumstances.

I consider early-term abortion to be justifiable homicide.

Sounds really bad, doesn't it?  And yet, I think I can support my argument, and further show that it's merely an attempt to put something that about half the people in the country support onto a semi-ethical foundation.

For fifty years now, ever since the technology became available, women have been able to control their fertility.  The ability to do this might not have resulted in breaking down the gender-specific roles we had in our culture.  We might, as a society, have decided that women should have remained homemakers in single-income families, even if those families had control over the number of children they had, including the ability to have none at all.  Indeed, there were plenty of arguments in the 70's and 80's to that very effect.  But those arguments failed.  We provided women largely equal opportunity in almost all aspects of modern life.  It dramatically improved our economic output, but it also made the two-earner family a requirement, because the economy adapted to the new economic power afforded to women.  We can't go back to a gender-segregated set of societal roles.  If we did, our economy would collapse.

An unwanted child is therefore now an economic disaster.  Not only does it affect the woman, who can't work effectively for a long period, it also affects her entire family.  A family living hand-to-mouth on two incomes can cease to be viable as the result of an extra child.  Loss of viability could mean dissolution of the family, inability to raise the existing children properly, homelessness, hopelessness, and who knows what other misery.


So the equality of women has led, irreversibly, to families with a lot less slack in their finances, and that in turn has led to the requirement that women be able to control their fertility.  That's largely achieved through contraception but when that fails, early-term abortion is a necessity.

Of course, women could just stop having sex, both in an out of wedlock, until they wanted children.  But again, we've crossed that bridge as a society and burned it behind us.  And let's be honest:  that was never really an option, was it?  Even before contraception, women had sex, sometimes with disastrous consequences.  But it's what human beings do.  Depriving half of the country to engage in an activity that makes almost everybody happier is a horrible idea.

But what of the unwanted child itself?  The "pro-life" (a term as deceptive as its opposite) argument is that the child's right to life trumps any amount of economic hardship for the family into which it is born.  That's a valid topic for debate, but I suggest that everybody who espouses that belief should spend some time with the chronically poor.  And there's nothing that will make a family chronically poor faster than having unwanted, unaffordable children.

Economically non-viable families produce socially non-viable children at an alarming rate.  Sure, lots of kids escape chronic poverty, but lots don't.  And those unlucky kids don't just grow up poor.  They grow up... stunted.  Stifled.  Hopeless.  And we're not just talking about the unwanted child here; that child's siblings suffer the same hardships, even though they're completely innocent of the action that dropped their family below the line.

Almost everybody, even the most ardently pro-life, believe that abortion is justifiable to save the life of the mother.  This makes sense:  if the mother dies, the fetus dies with her.  Better to sacrifice one life than two.  But why doesn't that argument apply to the family as a whole?  Where's the moral distinction?

More than anything else, that's why I believe that early-term abortion is justifiable homicide.  But let's not kid ourselves:  this is a bad thing, even if it's sometimes a necessary thing.

I don't think I'm going to change any minds among the pro-life faction here.  But let's return to the political now.  If for no other reason than that economy can't manage without it, abortion is going to continue.  The pro-life faction needs to understand this.  They're not going to win.

Even worse, though, the pro-lifers recently came close enough to succeeding that the other side, the political side that can't live without the cover of their "pro-choice" half-truth, had to consider the possibility that they might win.  This inevitably forces the pro-choicers to fight for every last inch of political ground.  No issue that even whiffs of "reproductive rights" can be ceded.  They'll mobilize every last resource to fight for the most repellent of practices, because they know that every time they lose a battle, the owners of the "pro-life" half-truth will advance, ready to conquer the next issue.  Neither side can back down.

And yet, I'll bet that an overwhelming majority of Americans would agree with the following:
  • Partial-birth abortions are an obscenity.  Unless the life of the mother is threatened, there should never be an excuse for this practice.  
  • If the baby from a medically necessary abortion is born alive, it needs to be treated as a baby.  That may mean that the mother has the right to make the agonizing choice to withhold medical care and watch her child struggle and die, or it may mean that we as a society are on the hook for endless care of a premature baby, if that's the mother's choice.  But we can't cross that line; if the child is born alive, it's born alive.
  • Short of medical necessity, there is no excuse for an abortion later than the end of the first trimester.  If the mother is an idiot and doesn't know she's pregnant, too bad.  She can put the baby up for adoption after she's carried it to term.  If we're going to tolerate abortion at all, we have to treat it as acceptable only as a failure of contraception, and that demands that the mother take some responsibility for understanding what's going on with her body and making a prompt decision.
  • Pregnant minor children are their parents' responsibility.  The parent decides what happens, just like with any other medical procedure.  If the parents decide that their daughter should carry a pregnancy to term, so be it.  After all, the baby will be their responsibility.  Withholding notification from parents is insane.
This looks like the best--possibly the only--compromise that's possible on this issue.  It's an important issue, even if it poisons every piece of political discourse that it touches.  Fundamentally, this is about what acts a society considers to be murder, and I can't think of a more important public policy topic.

But the social conservatives need to understand that abortion isn't going away.  The social and economic pressures to continue it are overwhelming.  Societies have the morals that they can afford, and our society can't afford the cost, both in economic and human terms, of unwanted children.  Until they understand this, and work out a firewall compromise like the one I've outlined above, they're going to continue to lose elections.  They got too close to succeeding in rolling back a set of laws whose existence most women depend upon, and they're never going to be given another chance to do so.

If they hold on to this, they will be politically annihilated, over and over again, until they stop.  And the net result will be a continued fraying of economic prosperity, liberty, and consensus culture.

Wednesday, November 7, 2012

The Joys of Unrequited Blogging

I noticed today that sometime in the last 24 hours I have exceeded 5000 all-time page views.

I've been writing my little screeds--550 of them now--into this blog now for a little more than five years.  5000 page views is a microscopic number for that amount of time, especially when you consider that the vast majority of those are robots or weird search-throughs.  I know that there are a handful of you out there who are actual readers, and maybe one or two that are regular readers.  Thanks for bearing with me.  You must find some of this stuff interesting or you wouldn't bother.  It makes a huge difference to know that I'm not always shouting into the void.

But, to be honest, I'd keep writing this even if there was nobody receiving.  I've always liked keeping up with the news and having an opinion about it.  I've found that you don't really know what your opinion is until you write it down.  Writing it down in a form that's fit for consumption by another human being gives me a little responsibility to be semi-clear, semi-coherent, and semi-civil.  All of those are nice personal qualities, deserving of periodic maintenance.

If you scroll back through my history, you'll find that my posting levels wax and wane, depending on what shiny object has currently attracted my attention.  Presidential campaigns tend to make me cranky, and I'll increase my output.  The result of presidential campaigns tends to make me depressed and post-averse for a while.  We'll see if that pattern holds up.  I'm not sure what would happen if somebody that I actually liked won.  Maybe one day I'll find out.  Hey, it could happen.

I post a three of four comments a week on other blogs.  No doubt the few of you who read this came to me through one of those.  I'm sure that the comments get more readers than the blog.  Maybe some day that will change.  Maybe not.

Sometimes I wonder what it would be like to run a successful blog.  I'm not sure I'd enjoy it.  I certainly don't desire it enough to market the blog, fool with search rankings, or write the inflammatory posts that seem necessary for the amateurs to be successful.  But it might be interesting if it just happened, but that's about as aspirational as I'm going to get.

So I'll just keep plugging away, if you don't mind--or even if you do mind.

Again, thanks.

Please Assume the "Brace" Position for Our Ride Over the Fiscal Cliff

In early September, I made another prediction on which I'd like to double down:
...Maybe the Republicans will suddenly decide to put the best interests of the nation ahead of political power games.  But the problem is that they honestly, truly believe that the endpoint of a successful second term for Obama results in national ruination.  Compared to that, a double-dip recession seems a small price to pay.  Furthermore, repeal of the middle-class tax cuts will mitigate the deficit caused by the recession, which will make the deficit hawks happy.  Bottom line:  the GOP is gonna play scorched-earth if Obama wins.
I don't think this is a good idea.  A double dip will put us way too close to a debt crisis for comfort.  But I'm not sure that the House GOP thinks that a debt crisis can be avoided any more.  Maybe they make the calculation that the deficit reductions from nuking the Bush tax cuts in toto are enough to stave off the debt crisis and give them the political whip hand.

Let's look at this a bit more closely:
  1. Short of an encyclical by His Holiness, Father Grover, pontiff of the Church of No Tax Increases Ever, most House Republicans are on pretty firm ground refusing to vote for any replacement to the expired Bush tax cuts, while still getting to execute a huge tax increase that will ultimately remove a big chunk of the deficit.
  2. Obama may offer to extend the Bush tax cuts again, but that has a certain Lucy-with-the-football-esque quality to it.  Better to get the pain out of the way early in Obama's second term so he gets blamed for the shambles, rather than getting pinned up against the next mid-term or presidential election.
  3. There is no upside to the Republicans for a grand bargain unless it's a clear win for them.  That would involve, at the very least, genuine tax reform and a deal to soft-land the transfer payments crisis at some viable percentage of total outlays (60% would be my guess).  I think Obama's too arrogant to take that deal.  (Minor prediction:  We'll hear at least one of the phrases, "Elections have consequences" or "I won" from the President some time in the next 3 months.)
  4. There is nothing but political upside for the GOP to doing nothing.  Things going to hell in a handbasket three months after Obama's reelection has a cause-and-effect association that will impress even the lowest of low information voters for a long time.  ("Long time" >= 4 years.)
In short, the only thing that saves us is if Obama is willing to take a big, yummy bite of Mr. Boehner's Famous Crap Sandwich.  ("Ya want dingleberries on that, Mr. President?" he asks with a big,--oh, what's that modifier?--grin.)  I'd love to believe that Obama has the character to understand his position and do the right thing, but I think we're way too close to his blind spot for him to exhibit the necessary self-awareness.

Oddly enough, tax reform could be Obama's salvation.  You can hide a huge tax increase under the guise of "reform" and nobody will be able to figure it out.  But it'll come at a price, one that will look oddly Romneyesque when the dust settles.  My proposal:
  • Across-the-board rate reduction of 5% in exchange for capped deductions and a reversion to the 20% capital gains rate at incomes above $500K.  Similar corporate tax reform.  The package should bring in $1 trillion over 10 years.
  • An additional $2 trillion out of Medicare and Social Security over 10 years.  The best solution would be to means-test both programs.  I don't think Obama can go for premium support after all the stupid things he said during the campaign, but he's gonna have to throw the GOP a bone that convinces them that he's not going to get the savings with price controls.
  • A targeted set of reforms to ACA:  a reduction in IPAB's power and smoothing over the small business penalty for hiring the 50th employee would go a long way.
  • From there, we're down to needing about an extra $1 trillion in cuts over 10 years.  This is within the zone of possible agreement between Obama and the GOP.
It's doable, but I have to say that the GOP has a massive strategic advantage going into this.

The Forecast: Moderate Gloom With Scattered Paranoia

Well, that was a bummer.

Over the past couple of months, I'd come to admire Mr. Romney immensely.  He ran an absolutely abysmal campaign up until October 1, and then suddenly got everything together.  He would have made a superb steward of the US executive branch.  Oh, well.

Now:  Did I call it, or what?
A boring presidential election is a ratings disaster.  It can't be allowed to happen.  So a Romney comeback is a financial imperative.

Furthermore, a Romney comeback is a damn good story.  Think of the drama as the Romney campaign reenergizes itself, retools its message, and claws its way back to within a whisker's breadth of its opponent.  It's the perfect third act.

It's also just the thing to show Obama at his pluckiest.  The beleaguered President, beset by a sea of troubles, slowly gains the upper hand over his rival against all odds, only to become complacent and have things almost slip away.  But at the last moment, he too rights his campaign, just in time to squeak out a win.

All is right with the world.  The media get the outcome they want, and their network executives get to take home their bonuses.
And now, for the paranoia:  If it weren't for Obama tanking the first debate, there would have been no drama to the race.  Obama would have coasted to at least a six point victory, and nobody would have watched the news for the crucial last month of the campaign.

So, if you were a media executive with access to the highest levels of the Obama campaign, and you could convince the President that the election was in the bag no matter what, do you think you could convince him to go limp for the first debate?

Nah.  Surely not. 

Right?


Sunday, November 4, 2012

Intrade, Sunday Afternoon

Note that Obama, after rising substantially over the last couple of weeks, is now starting to tail off again:


Still not looking good, but you'd expect to be seeing things rising close to 100% if there were a real consensus yet.  A negative first derivative is a good thing.

UPDATE 11/07/12:  I'm retroactively nominating this post for this year's First Annual Radical Moderation Whistling in the Dark Award, for the most willful denial of reality written down this year.

Saturday, November 3, 2012

Party Identification, Revisited

Nate Sliver is now contending, with fairly strong evidence, that the only way that Romney can win is if there is statistical bias.  By this he means a systematic sampling error, rather than some kind of partisan bias.

Today we also have an NBC/WSJ/Marist poll from Ohio showing Obama with a 51 to 45 lead.  (Full PDF here.)

All of this got me to thinking about the brouhaha back in September about party identification.

Back then, there were a whole bunch of Republican proxies raising questions about Democrats being oversampled in the polls (all rapidly southbound for Romney at the time).  The argument was that pollsters appeared to be filtering likely voters based on a party identification model that looked weird, given the GOP's strength in 2010 vs. 2008.

It was a bad argument, because party identification isn't used to filter likely voters.  However, party identification is a commonly asked question in presidential preference polls.  One would expect party ID to be somewhat correlated with presidential preference, but not completely.  As a general rule, party ID should be a lot less volatile than presidential preference.

This is where things get kinda strange.  Take, for example, the Marist poll above.  It found party ID to be 38% Democratic, 29% Republican, and 32% independent.  When you compare that to exit polling in Ohio in 2008 and 2010, here's what you get:

Party ID2008 Exit Ohio2010 Exit Ohio11/03/12 Marist Ohio
Democrat393638
Republican313629
Independent302832


Obama won handily in 2008 and the Democrats made significant gains in the House and Senate, so a +8 spread for the Democrats sounded reasonable.  And, in 2010, note that the zero spread between the two parties indicated a sharp shift to the Republicans, as the election results confirmed.

But look at the Marist results for November 3 likely voters: you wind up with a spread of Democrats +9, even greater than that of 2008.  Now, I'm willing to believe that the GOP isn't as strong in Ohio as it was in 2010 but, given the state of the country and Romney's rapid (and dramatic!) rise following the debates, the GOP is almost certainly not doing worse than it did in 2008.  Something's wrong.

Now, I am not saying that the pollsters have done biased filtering for likely voters.  These people live and die on their professional reputations, and they're simply not going to risk going into the tank by applying any illegitimate filter criterion, let alone one with such a strong coefficient.

But there is something profoundly wrong with these numbers.  They don't make sense.  Why?

The only answer I can come up with is that there is indeed some sort of systematic sampling error at work.  Maybe it's a problem with the cell phone model.  Maybe it's just that the people who will actually answer a survey these days are very, very odd.  Maybe it's something more subtle.  But the party ID numbers don't pass the smell test, and that means the sampling is weird.

Given that I think that Nate Silver is correct, this is very good news for Romney.  Or at least not bad news.  Or... news.  My conclusions have a high standard error.

Wednesday, October 31, 2012

Benghazi

This is one of those issues where I find myself walking a narrow path between cynicism and naivete.  My inner cynic knows that all administrations lie about national security in general and war in particular, so I'm not surprised that the Obama Administration is spewing contradictory stories to sow confusion like an octopus squirts ink.

But my inner naif keeps telling me that the American people deserve a straightforward accounting before they vote.  (Well, before a lot of them vote.  Some of us have already pulled the trigger.)

So let's see if we can organize the giant mudslide of data into something vaguely coherent.

This much we seem to know:

  1. A 16-man security team, after having its tour extended for four months, was pulled out of Libya on August 14.
  2. There were at least two requests for enhanced security that went from State's regional security manager to his superiors.  Both were either ignored or denied.
  3. The US consulate was attacked twice prior to the 9/11/12 attack, although one of the attacks was conducted by recently fired Libyan guards.  The British ambassador had also been attacked and the Brits had withdrawn their mission.
  4. There was no spontaneous riot at the consulate.  The attackers moved directly on the consulate with small arms and at least RPGs.  By the time of the battle at the annex, they had a mortar crew in place.  We do not know if the attack was spontaneous in response to the rioting elsewhere, a pre-planned attack that was moved up to capitalize on the riots, or a planned attack that may have incited the riots elsewhere for greater impact.
  5. There was a drone overhead throughout most of the attack.  The annex was feeding situation reports in real time back to at least the CIA.
  6. Panetta says he was aware of the attack shortly after it began, but the intelligence was too poor to mount a rescue.
  7. The President says that he directed has National Security team to "make sure we are securing our personnel and doing what we need to".
  8. Fox News reports that the CIA annex asked for permission to go to the aid of the consulate and were told to stand downDavid Ignatius's reporting indicates that this command may have only lasted a half hour while the CIA checked with friendly militias.  These two reports are somewhat in conflict.
  9. The same Fox News report indicates that after the battle for the annex began, repeated requests for military support were made to the CIA.  These requests was denied.  The CIA denies this.  The same report indicates that one of the men in the protective detail had painted targets from the roof of the annex with a ground laser designator.
  10. On 9/12/12, Obama did indeed use the words "acts of terror" but if he was referring to the Benghazi attack, jeez, talk about burying the lede.  Read the transcript for yourself.
  11. The official Presidential Daily Brief version of the attack still referred to protests over the film the day before Susan Rice went on the Sunday shows, so she may have been acting on the best official assessment she had.  Per this report, the CIA reassessed at just about the time Rice was floating the "protesting the film" story to anybody who'd put her on camera.
  12. Jay Carney stated that the attack was in protest of the movie on 9/20/12, long after the PDB had been updated.  Obama's UN speech of 9/25/12 never mentioned terrorism but referred to the protests and the movie repeatedly.
  13. Carter Ham's replacement as commander of AFRICOM was announced on 10/18/12.  Per Jennifer Griffin, this action had been planned for some time, contrary to speculation that he was relieved while attempting to send in a rescue.
This much we either suspect or can infer:
  1. It's possible that the White House was unaware of the requests for extra security but, given the IED attack, the attack that destroyed one of the walls around the consulate, and the June attack on the British ambassador, it seems incredible (aka "unbelievable") that the White House didn't know that there was a problem.  They clearly didn't act.
  2. It's possible that the CIA stovepiped the situational reports and didn't share them with the Pentagon, but it's inconceivable that they withheld them from the White House.  Given Panetta's comments, it's almost certain that DoD was looped in pretty early.
  3. Several bloggers, most notably Blackfive,  commented that nobody paints a target with a GLD unless there's an air asset in the area, because the GLD is visible in night vision goggles and gives away your position.  This seems to contradict statements that the drones were unarmed and/or that no other armed air assets were in the area.  If that's true, then somebody told them to hold fire, which could only have come from the White House, the Pentagon, or General Ham, the AFRICOM commander.
  4. While it's possible that Susan Rice didn't get the word, either deliberately or inadvertently, the White House must have known that there was more to this than a riot that got out of hand.  And there's no way that they kept Jay Carney in the dark on this without some ulterior motive.
There are some important outstanding questions:
  1. Why were the security requests ignored?  Was there a diplomatic rationale?  Was there a political rationale (i.e. because extra security weakened the narrative of an acceptably orderly aftermath of the Arab Spring, or that organized Islamist militants were in decline)?
  2. What was the nature of the attack in Benghazi? Was it pre-planned or extemporaneous to capitalize on the protests about the move?
  3. Why did the Obama Administration muddy the waters so much after the attack?  Was it incompetence, political strategy, or something else?
And, finally, we can make some judgements:
  1. The President has allowed a massive management failure to occur on his watch.  There is some sort of serious dysfunction between State, CIA, and DoD, both in escalating threat assessments to the President and in managing an emerging military situation.
  2. The most charitable thing that can be said about the messaging in the aftermath of the attack is that the White House was hopelessly confused.  More likely, it knew it had a political liability on its hands and it muddied the waters as much as possible, while deliberately burying the truth in a bunch of untruths that could plausibly be interpreted as the "fog of war".
  3. The President has been ignorant or at least incurious about how well his foreign policy narrative jibes with reality.  That disconnect has cost American lives and severely diminished American soft power.
Is this a disqualifying event for a second Obama term?  Not all by itself.  But it is a rather stunning sequence of situational misjudgement, risk-averse crisis management, and craven obfuscation.